Share this article: Facebooktwitterredditpinterestlinkedinmail

22 February 2018

Alasdair Smith is an Emeritus Professor of Economics at the University of Sussex, and is a Fellow of the UK Trade Policy Observatory.

This week  Economists for Free Trade (EfFT) suggested that if the post-Brexit UK were to embrace unilateral free trade (UFT), the net effect of Brexit would be positive rather than negative. Earlier work on unilateral free trade has focused exclusively or largely on tariff reductions – and this latest paper has the merit of recognising that border costs and non-tariff measures (NTMs) should be brought into the analysis. Unfortunately, as Jonathan Portes and Chris Giles have observed, the EfFT assumptions are not credible.[1]

In our Briefing Paper ‘Which Manufacturing Sectors are Most Vulnerable to Brexit?’, published on 6 February 2018, we used a disaggregated economic model to consider the effects of different versions of Brexit on the UK manufacturing industry. We found that for manufacturing industry as a whole (and for most manufacturing sectors), all variants of Brexit are likely to be costly, raising prices for consumers and reducing output for producers.

To evaluate the predictions of the EfFT on the potential benefits of Brexit if accompanied by unilateral free trade, we have now run a UFT Brexit scenario in our model. The fact that we consider only manufactures is helpful to the analysis, because unilateral tariff reductions have no meaning in services trade where tariffs are not applied. Trade in goods is where EfFT have their best shot.

UFT is meaningful only in the context of a hard Brexit in which the UK exits the Customs Union, the Single Market, and the FTA with the EU. The EU is not going to roll forward any of the current trade arrangements with the UK if the UK is going to remove all tariffs on agricultural products, on textiles and clothing, and on cars. Our benchmark should therefore be a hard Brexit.

What do we find? A hard Brexit with no deals with the EU or the EU’s FTA partners would raise UK prices by 5%; and that’s a simple measure of the cost of Brexit to UK consumers of manufactures. If, however, the UK were additionally to adopt unilateral free trade, the cost of Brexit would be halved, to 2.5%. But even with UFT, Brexit is costly.

On the producer side, it is widely recognised that UFT has a negative impact. We project that a hard Brexit with no UFT might reduce overall demand for UK manufactures by 5.5% (with the likelihood of larger long-run reductions as some producers decided to exit the UK). A hard Brexit plus UFT more than doubles the hit on UK manufacturing, to over 12%.

The difference between our negative projections and the positive projections of EfFT lie in how we model post-Brexit trade barriers.

In our modelling of the UFT Brexit scenario, we assume that while the UK sets zero tariffs on all imports of manufactures from the EU and from all non-EU countries, these tariff cuts are not reciprocated. The EU imposes tariffs on imports from the UK at the rates that it currently imposes on countries with which it does not have Free Trade Agreements, and those countries with whom the UK currently has Free Trade Agreements as a member of the EU do the same. This is the same set of assumptions as EfFT made for non-EU countries; their assumptions about UK-EU tariffs are not entirely clear.

Assumptions about NTMs require some care. We assume that currently UK-EU trade is not impeded by NTMs (because both are part of the Single Market),  that imports from FTA partner countries face low levels of NTMs, and that NTMs are high with respect to all other partners. In the UFT Brexit policy simulation we assume that in the spirit of UFT the UK will treat imports from most countries as acceptable from a regulatory perspective. We model this by assuming that NTMs on imports into the UK from all countries are set at the lower level that apply to trade flows between countries that have FTAs and that therefore recognise each other’s regulatory regimes. This contrasts with EfFT’s unrealistic assumption of zero NTMs on UK imports. NTMs on imports cannot be zero – the UK is not entering a single market arrangement with the whole world in which imports will face no regulatory requirements at the border.

In a similar vein, while EfFT assume zero border costs, we assume, both in the base and in the policy simulation, that all trade flows to and from the UK face border costs of 3.5% (at the low end of the literature estimates). Even if there are no tariffs to be collected on imports, border controls will be needed to ensure that regulatory and legal requirements are met. (Is it credible that trucks loaded with heroin, dangerous toys, and diseased agricultural produce should enter the UK uninspected and unhindered?).  With the UK out of the EU, border controls will be required to collect VAT on imports too. With the UK out of the Single Market, there would be border inspections of imports from the EU as well as from the rest of the world.

EfFT assume that the approximately half of our imports that currently come from the EU free of tariffs, of regulatory barriers and of border costs will continue to arrive on the same terms. The other half of our imports which currently face tariffs, NTBs and border costs will – on EfFT’s assumption – face none of these costs, and the UK economy will unambiguously gain from lower-cost imports.

We have run our model also on these incredible assumptions and find that in this scenario, UK output of manufactures falls by only 6%, and prices fall by 2% giving a modest gain to consumers from Brexit. This confirms that the difference between us and EfFT does not lie in arcane details of the respective models, but in our different assumptions about trade costs.

Our more realistic analysis of a hard Brexit plus UFT is that on non-EU imports the UK will apply zero tariffs, face reduced NTBs, and unchanged border costs; while on EU imports, tariffs will stay at zero, but NTMs and border costs are introduced. The simple arithmetic is that the reduction in costs on non-EU imports does not compensate for losing the easy access to EU imports that results from the Customs Union and Single Market. The only way that EfFT can obtain a positive impact on the UK economy is to make assumptions which, as Chris Giles suggests, are simply ‘absurd’.

Does unilateral free trade offer the UK the prospect of a costless hard Brexit? In a word, no.

 

Footnotes

[1] In addition and in support of their conclusions the EfFT cites the work of Ciurak et.al. (2015), who they claim find a positive outcome from unilateral free trade of 0.8% of GDP. However, and somewhat worryingly they have failed to read Ciurak et.al. properly. The gain of 0.8% is relative to the losses from leaving the EU and Ciurak et.al. make it quite clear in their conclusions that “our estimate of UK unilateral liberalization is a gain of 0.75% of GDP; this still leaves the UK underwater relative to the cost of Brefta”. Hence they conclude the net effect is negative.

 

Disclaimer:

The opinions expressed in this blog are those of the author alone and do not necessarily represent the opinions of the University of Sussex or UK Trade Policy Observatory.

Republishing guidelines

The UK Trade Policy Observatory believes in the free flow of information and encourages readers to cite our materials, providing due acknowledgement. For online use, this should be a link to the original resource on our website. We do not publish under a Creative Commons license. This means you CANNOT republish our articles online or in print for free.

3 Comments

  • Rob Moss says:

    You’re ignoring comparative advantage. Subsidising farming and taxing your own citizens obviously raises food prices. The same goes for any other industry. If it turns out that our manufacturing industry collapses in the face of UFT – great! That scarce resource, human labour, is released from its current unproductive shackles and is released to go and do something more useful. That’s the point of UFT – the elimination of useless companies and probably entire industries, because someone else can do that cheaper and better elsewhere. It simply maximises our economic output, with the added benefit that it’s the little guy who wins, not the corporate fat cat, just as happened in 1846.

  • You ask: “Is it credible that trucks loaded with heroin, dangerous toys, and diseased agricultural produce should enter the UK uninspected and unhindered?”

    The short answer is “no”, and your assumption that the UK will need new border controls to counter such a “threat” from our EU trading partners is unfounded fear. The Union is not about to lower its law-enforcement and production standards, and to the extent that goods shipped to the UK will be subject to Union export controls, the EU will be less likely to send such undesirable goods to us after 29 March 2019.

  • RICHARD MOORE says:

    Having a total unilateral FTA is the only option. It puts the onus back on the EU and the Irish regarding the border. The EU would then have to instruct the Irish to build border customs posts and even if this came out of the EU coffers the Irish would not want them. The actual cost of free trade (even if not reciprocated) would be £3.4 billion lost revenue on non EU goods and potentially £2 billion on EU goods. However it is likely that WTO tariffs applied to businesses in the UK exporting to the EU that would cost £3 billion here could be refunded to business so long as they are working in the national interest. Subsidies to farmers would also need to be given especially as the EU will dump foods cheaply into the UK to try and undermine us economically. We should declare that the free trade is for one year but with view to make it permanent. This would be cheaper than buying off the EU with £39 billion. Meanwhile if the value of the pound fell (most likely in the short term) then imports would be less competitive. This would snooker the whole of the approach of the EU to the point that they’d agree a lot more.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *